My review of Sumner
This will be coming out in The Journal of the History of Economic Thought, but probably not for another year or so. In the meantime, you get it first:
___________________________________________
Sumner, Scott B. The Midas Paradox: Financial Markets,
Government Policy Shocks, and the Great Depression. The Independent
Institute, 2015. xviii, 507 pp. Hardcover, $37.95.
The Midas Paradox
is the result of Scott Sumner’s many years of contemplating the causes of the
Great Depression. Sumner adopts a novel “gold market approach” in this work,
holding that the demand side shocks largely responsible for the worldwide
economic downturn were increases in state and private actors’ desire to hoard
gold. The “paradox” of the title arises from the logical fact that, with a
relatively fixed amount of gold available, it is impossible for all market
participants to increase their gold holdings simultaneously. When they try to
do so, the result is instead a decrease in economic activity.
The heart of the book is nine chapters of detailed
historical analysis of the macroeconomic history from 1929 through 1938,
employing Sumner’s gold market approach. To brutally abbreviate Sumner’s
narrative, in 1929, monetary policy mistakes, particularly the failure of
France and the United States to print an amount of currency commensurate with
their rapidly increasing gold stocks, led to the stock market crash and banking
panics. Roosevelt’s decision to inflate by taking the US off the gold standard
spurred a recovery that was nipped in the bud by the NIRA’s high wage policies,
which delivered a supply side shock. The economy recovered again, albeit less
than it might have, due to repeated attempts to raise wages by the Roosevelt
administration. Then the final Great Depression setback occurred when private
gold hoarding caused the “Roosevelt depression” of 1937.
Sumner is a diligent researcher, so there is no point in
this reviewer disputing the facts on the ground as he describes them. Instead,
this review will focus on the methods he uses in handling these facts, which
sometimes oscillate uneasily between historical and theoretical analysis.
Throughout this work, Sumner is a strong proponent of the
efficient markets hypothesis and the “wisdom of crowds.” For instance, he
criticizes those who think anyone can reliably outguess financial markets: “A modern example of this conundrum
occurred when many pundits blamed the Fed for missing a housing bubble that was
also missed by the financial markets” (p. 12).
What should
we make of this statement? We can divide bubble theories into three broad
categories: collective irrationality theories, partial information theories,
and prisoner's dilemma theories. In collective irrationality theories, a “mania”
gets going in some market, and market participants buy because they are carried
away by their “animal spirits.” Per these theories, someone outside the market
(such as the Fed!) might be able to spot the bubble precisely because they are
not swayed by the emotions influencing market participants.
In partial
information theories, a bubble can occur when a random price movement is
mistakenly taken by market participants, who lack perfect knowledge, as a sign
that someone else knows more than they do. Therefore they follow this random
jiggle, leading others to follow it as well. Theoretically at least, if we have
a bubble of this sort, an agency like the Fed might have better information at its disposal than market
participants, and so be able to spot the bubble.
Finally, in
the prisoner's dilemma theories, market participants may be well aware that a
bubble is inflating, but their best strategy is to try to profit from the
bubble as long as it is expanding. Since these theories typically posit that a “big
player” (e.g., the Fed) is actually causing the bubble, the Fed is also clearly
capable of ceasing to cause it at any point in time.
Perhaps what
Sumner is thinking is that, although there may have been bubble in the housing
market, the market for, say, mortgage-backed securities ought to have been
acting on this fact, if it was detectable at all. But it is hard to see how
such action in the MBS market wouldn't have prevented the housing bubble
itself, since cutting off the flow of mortgage funding would seem likely to
have done so.
So, perhaps
Sumner just meant, “Bubbles can't exist, because markets won't allow them.” But
if so, he phrased this oddly.
It is hard to
know what to make of some Sumner’s other claims as well. For example, he
writes:
Romer argued that the 1929 stock market crash sharply reduced consumer confidence, and that this was a major factor depressing aggregate demand. But the quite similar stock market crash in 1987 seemed to have no impact at all on economic growth, suggesting that the direct impact of stock prices on real output is certainly very small. (p. 39)
What we have here is an oscillation between an
historical mode of explanation and a scientific one. Science deals
in generalizations, and has nothing to say about specific events other
than citing them as instances of its generalizations. (“The arrow will fall
back to earth, as it was shot in the air with less than escape velocity.”)
History, on the other hand, deals with particulars, and a resort to scientific
generalizations is at most a stopgap in an historical explanation, filling in
where we lack actual historical knowledge. (“Although we have no evidence for
what happened in that battle, the Egyptians probably won, as armies with such a
preponderance of force typically do.”)
But a stopgap generalization like that above
cannot be used to defease an historical narrative based on actual evidence: it
is silly to write, “It is unlikely that some obscure Macedonian named Alexander
conquered the Persian Empire, as armies facing such an imbalance in force are
almost always defeated.” We are dealing with extensive evidence that these
things did happen, and we can only reasonably dispute that evidence
with other historical evidence
showing, for instance, a widespread conspiracy to fake the existence of
Alexander.
So even if, somehow (based on only two cases!)
Sumner has established a scientific generalization that “generally, stock
market crashes have very little impact on real output,” that says nothing about
the actual historical evidence for whether, in the particular case of the Great
Depression, the 1929 crash had a large impact. What starts a panic in one crowd
in one place and time may be shrugged off nonchalantly by another crowd in
another place and time; events are what they are interpreted to be by human
beings, and human interpretation is not constant.
Or consider the following passage:
On June 4, 1928, the New York Times (p. 4) reported 'Credit Curb Hinted by Reserve Board.' The market actually rose slightly on June 5, but then, over the following week, the Dow plunged 7 percent. Policy news ought to be incorporated into securities prices almost immediately, and thus, it is unclear whether the Fed's announcement had any impact on the markets. (47)
This is an odd way to do
historical research: one goes in knowing what should happen—policy news ought
to be incorporated into securities prices almost immediately—and then creates
the facts—“it is unclear whether the Fed's announcement had any impact”—based
on the pre-existing theory. There
is a sound historical way to
determine whether the news about the Fed was what “caused” this drop: detailed
examination of the journals, memoirs, letters, newsletters and so on of stock
market participants of that time, seeking to determine if this was really what
was worrying them.
Similarly,
Sumner writes, “in order to understand the October [1929] crash, one needed to
explain why it would have been sensible for investors to be highly optimistic in
September 1929, and somewhat pessimistic in November 1929” (60-61).
Again, Sumner
is introducing his conclusions as a criterion for what facts will be
acceptable. Of course, no one embarks on an attempt to explain some historical
episode with a “blank slate”: every effort at understanding is an effort to
understand better what is to some extent already understood. There is nothing
wrong with Sumner starting with the hypothesis that investors were “sensible”
in September 1929, and seeing if it holds up. But here Sumner posits their
being sensible, not as a conjecture to be explored, but as a given which any
explanation must incorporate. And given that is a pre-condition he has placed
on any acceptable explanation of what occurred, it is inevitable that the end
result of his inquiry will be that they were, indeed, sensible.
While the
history Sumner describes is complex, he has done a good job of convincing the
reader that it is not needlessly so: there was indeed not a single event, “the
Great Depression,” but a whole series of demand- and supply-side shocks that
continually battered the economy.
Following his
historical narrative, Sumner concludes his book with three chapters drawing
broader conclusions from his history. In the first, he contemplates the impact
of the Great Depression on twentieth-century macroeconomics. The most important
conclusion he reaches here is that the Keynesian elevation of fiscal over
monetary policy is based on a misreading of the ineffectiveness of the Fed’s
open-market purchases in 1932, which ineffectiveness, he contends, was due to
gold outflows, and not a “liquidity trap.”
In this
chapter, he makes a strong argument for the importance of history for theory,
claiming:
While working on this project I have gradually come to the conclusion that modern macroeconomics, macro history, and the history of thought are a seamless whole; it is impossible to really understand any one filed without also having deep knowledge of the other two. (357)
His next chapter analyzes the
causes of the Great Depression. Although
Sumner is a self-described ‘libertarian’ his policy conclusion stemming from
his study is nonetheless pro-intervention:
If there is a root cause of the Great Depression, it lies somewhere in the painful birth of the modern world, the difficulty that societies had letting go of the “barbarous relic,” and moving to a more mature, and interventionist, monetary policy regime. (393).
Whether this represents
admirable flexibility or culpable wishy-washiness, I leave it to the reader to
decide.
Sumner also makes
a very interesting observation of “the lessons of history” in this chapter:
This leads to another cautionary observation about the “lessons of history.” Either of the two policy counterfactuals [of tighter or looser monetary policy] for 1928-1929 might have led to a smaller 'Great Depression,' but in retrospect the undervaluation of gold made some sort of downturn almost inevitable. Had either alternative strategy been followed, and a modest depression resulted, that alternative would have almost certainly received historical censure. (397)
Sumner offers as an analogy
the allied policy towards Germany after World War I. He argues, plausibly I
think, that Allied policy was just about perfectly bad. If Allied peace terms
had been more forgiving, Germany would have recovered better, and the appeal of
the Nazis would have been blunted. But if the policy had been even harsher than
it was, then, Nazis or no Nazis, Germany would have been too weak to
remilitarize the Rhineland, threaten Czechoslovakia, and so on.
A final, minor
gripe I have is that, for those of us not as versed as Sumner in the monetary
institutions and history of the late international gold standard, it would have
been useful to have a bit more explanation of the technical details of what was
occurring. For example, he mentions “gold sterilization” several times, without
ever describing what this consists of. The reader can, of course, look this up
elsewhere, but since the book is not aimed exclusively at specialists, why not
briefly describe the procedure?
In summary, Sumner
has written an excellent and thought provoking book that should be read by all
students of the Great Depression. His unusual focus on the gold market and the
wealth of detail he presents on what actually occurred during the late 1920s
and the 1930s certainly will repay careful study.
Comments
Post a Comment